When Americans vote in November unemployment will be below 6%

Friday’s US labour market report rightly got a lot of media attention globally. The spike in US unemployment to 15% surely is historical and tells us quite a bit about just how big a shock has hit the US and the global economy.

However, where most commentators are wrong is assuming that this has to be seen as a normal recession. I on the other hand would argue that this has little to do with a normal recession. In fact I am increasingly thinking that the use of the term ‘recession’ is a misnomer in relation to this crisis.

Back in April I argued in my blog post ‘All set for a fast recovery after the ‘Great Lockdown’ argued that this crisis primarily should be seen as an unplanned and very unpleasant ‘vacation’. 

The IMF has called it the ‘Great Lockdown’ and I find this term very telling. Economies around the world have been locked down – either by governments or by voluntary behaviour by people who want to protect themselves against the coronavirus. 

Most people don’t really think about it, but most industrialised economies in the world every year goes through large “recessions” in the form of a major drop in economic activity. This happens both on the supply side as for example Southern Europeans go on Summer vacation typically in August or with private consumption as it fluctuates wildly before and after Christmas. 

We don’t see articles about this in the financial media and the reason is of course that we know this is happening. It happens every year. So nobody cares – we plan for it so it isn’t an economic problem. 

The lockdowns – boths by government intervention and voluntary social distancing – wasn’t preplanned and that’s why it has created a major economic disruption.

But that said, if we instead of sensationalising it, take a look in our economic textbooks and look at economic history then we will realise that economies return to ‘normal’ very fast after ‘vacations’ (also very unpleasant vacations).

The reason demand shocks take long to ‘disappear’ is that prices and wages are sticky and that economic policy reacts too slowly or insufficiently. But that is not the problem with supply shocks – they very rarely have longer-term effects. 

In fact that was the problem with the entire idea in the so-called Real Business Cycle (RBC) models that became popular (to discuss) in the early 1990s – it simply was impossible to show empirically that supply shocks would have very long-lasting effects on economic activity and certainly no long-lasting impact on labour markets. 

So when I in the headline argues that US unemployment will be back below 6% in November then it is simply because that is what the economic textbook tells us – market economies adjust fast to supply shocks.

This is essentially the point I also was making in my blog post in April, but I am happy to repeat it and I haven’t become more negative since then. The labour report, while it was horrible wasn’t the least surprising. 

We have known for weeks that US unemployment would spike to these levels so I really haven’t become more worried about my forecast for a sharp recovery in economic activity in the US towards the end of the year.

In this blog post I will present three more arguments – other than the purely theoretical arguments I have just repeated – why I believe that unemployment will soon be down to a level close to before the lockdown-shock hit. 

The markets is telling us so

When I back in 2011 coined the term ‘market monetarism’ is was because (now self-declared) market monetarists like Scott Sumner and David Beckworth and myself believe that financial markets tend to be efficient and hence reflect all available information about the outlook for the economy and that markets therefore will be the best available ‘forecast’ for the outlook for the economy and that policy makers should utilize this information when they conduct policy. 

This also means that market monetarist economists to a much larger extent than more traditional macroeconomists tend to look at financial markets when they try to forecast what will happen in the economy going forward.

And if we look at what markets have been telling us since the second half of March it is that this is not a demand shock. Market inflation expectations have first rebounded and then stabilised after the initial first shock and due to the actions of the Federal Reserve. 

And the stock market is telling us the same story. The US stock market is not back at the levels we saw in late February but we have made a significant recovery as markets got better visibility about the outlook for the spread of the coronavirus and the Fed demonstrated that it would not allow a new debt-deflation spiral to set-in. 

To me the US stock market, while sometimes wrong, is a fairly reliable indicator of future growth in US nominal income (NGDP) and normally fluctuations in NGDP growth cause fluctuations in US unemployment so we should expect the stock market to be a fairly good indicator of the US labour market as well. 

We can illustrate this with a simple xy-graph with changes (%y/y) in US stock prices (Wilshire 500) versus percentage-point changes (y/y) in the US unemployment rate lagged six months.   

Unemployment stock market

As we see there has historically been a fairly strong inverse relationship between the development in the US stock market and in US unemployment (over the coming 6 months). In the graph I use data going back to 1982. 

It is not hard to spot the outlier – the US stock market “failed” to predict the sharp rise in US unemployment we saw in April. 

One conclusion of course could be that the market is just plain wrong and the situation is much worse than the collective wisdom of the market says it is.

This essentially what a lot of commentators are saying at the moment – the market has become way too optimistic and it is all driven by “Fed liquidity”.

Well, I trust the market where investors have money on the line rather than pundits.

So what is that market telling us? 

Presently the broad US stock market is down around 2% over the past year and given the historical statistical relationship that would (based on a simple linear regression) imply that US unemployment should be up around 0.5%-point in November (compared to November 2019). This would imply US unemployment at 4% in November – somewhat lower than 6%. 

Obviously this is meant as an illustration rather than an actual forecast, but the overall story is nonetheless that judging from the US stock market the sharp increase in unemployment we saw in March and April is going to be temporary and unemployment will soon be back to normal levels. 

Hence, the markets are presently pricing that this will not be a long-last economic downturn and hence the increase in unemployment will be temporary and this naturally brings us to the next topic – most of the increase in unemployment is driven by people who have been laid off temporarily. 

Most layoffs are temporary

Historically around 10% of US unemployment has been made up by workers temporarily laid off from their jobs. 

However, if we look at the US unemployment in April 78% of all unemployed had the status of being temporarily laid off.

This means that essentially the entire increase in US unemployment in April was due to temporary lay-offs. We see that in the graph below. 

What I here call ‘core unemployment’ is unemployment minus the unemployed who has been temporarily laid-off. 

Core unemployment

We see here that ‘core’ unemployment actually has been more or less unchanged over the last couple of months (also in April) around 3.2%

This contrast sharply with the recessions of 2001 and 2008-9 where the number of temporarily laid-off workers didn’t increase at all, but core unemployment rose sharply. Both the recessions of 2001 and 2008-9 were recessions caused by demand shocks. 

If we, however, go back to the recessions of 1973-74, 1979-80 and 1990 we see that the share of temporary laid-off workers increased initially during all of these three recessions. 

What did all of these three recessions have in common? They initially all were triggered by a sharp increase in oil prices – hence, a negative supply shock.

While an oil price shock is something very different from a lockdown both are nonetheless negative shocks to the production (supply) side of the economy. 

This basically means that workers are being laid-off not because they have become too “expensive” relative to output prices (that is what is happening with a demand shock), but because the cost of OTHER inputs have increased. In the case of lockdowns simply because production basically is outlawed in certain sectors. 

Hence, a supply shock is not about prices and wage rigidity as I discussed above and this means that workers have not been ‘priced out of the market’ and should therefore be expected to return to work once production gets up and running again. 

During the first oil crisis the spike in ‘temporary unemployed’ lasted a bit more than a year while it took only around 9-10 months to get back to ‘normal’ during the second oil crisis. 

However, it should be noted that both during the first and the second oil crisis monetary conditions were tightened in response to rising headline (supply-side) inflation, which caused nominal demand growth to slow. Said in another way, on top of the supply shocks we got a negative demand shock. 

This isn’t the case this time around – the Fed has responded to the crisis by moving to ease monetary conditions and even though market inflation expectations are too low (lower the Fed’s 2% inflation target) the Fed nonetheless has stabilized inflation expectations

This means that once the lockdowns come to an end people will be able to return to work – not necessarily to their old jobs and not necessarily in the sectors they used to work in, but the reason they haven’t been working is not that their reservation wage were higher than their productivity so there is little reason why we shouldn’t see the share of temporarily unemployed come down very fast in the coming few months.

Another illustration of this is to look at initial jobless claims in different US states. 

I have looked at some of the hardest hit states where there also have been fairly strict lockdowns and States which have been less hard hit and also a State where there hasn’t been a lockdown (Utah). 

For a comparison I have also included the state of Louisiana, but with the data from 2005 when the state was hard hit by Hurricane Katrina.   

Claims

When we look at the data we see a very different pattern than what we would see normally during a recession where initially jobless claims keep rising months. In fact during the recession in 2008-9 initial jobless claims rose for more than a year. 

This time it is different and as we see the initial jobless claims numbers now behave much more like a shock like Hurricane Katrina in 2005. 

In fact so far the pattern has been very similar for most States – an initial sharp (very sharp) increase in jobless numbers for a couple of weeks followed by a relative sharp drop in initial jobless numbers thereafter. 

So far the numbers more or less have tracked the ‘Katrina pattern’ and if that continues we should expect ‘claims’ to be back to normal levels by the end of June. At that time we should already have seen US unemployment numbers having started to come down significantly. 

Consumption will rebound sharply – the money is there

I have for some time when talking to the media or with clients been making the argument that this crisis primarily is a supply shock and as long as the Fed (and other central banks) are doing their job of ensuring nominal stability when the economy should rebound very fast once we around the world move out of the ‘lockdown’.

However, most people (even many economists) tend to have a rather rudimentary perspective on economics and what they observe is that since private consumption is down and therefore (they believe) should GDP be – whether nominal or real doesn’t seem to matter. 

So even though I don’t really think it is important how the GDP‘cake’ is sliced in terms of aggregate nominal demand I will nonetheless try to address the issues of private consumption. 

Basically I believe that it makes most sense to think of private consumption on a macro level within Milton Friedman’s permanent income hypothesis. 

Over time private consumption is determined by permanent income expectations. So if our expectations about further permanent income decline we will tend to spend less.

Obviously on a micro-level one can have all kinds of reservations about Friedman’s permanent income hypothesis, but I still think it is the best we got. 

That essentially also means that we can think of how much each of us spends in a given week or month as reflecting the ‘targeted private consumption’ we have, which in turn reflects our expectations about permanent income. 

However, we do also change our spending depending on a lot of other things – we spend more when we are on vacations and during weekends. The same goes for holidays like Christmas. And then we spend less during other periods. 

From time to time we don’t hit our ‘targeted’ consumption. For example if you have planned to buy a new laptop, but it turned out that the model you wanted was sold out and you now have to wait another month. Or the opposite happens – you find something you have been looking for on eBay and simply has to buy it – even though that increases your spending above your targeted spending. 

With this ‘model’ in mind I think we can understand what has been happening with US private consumption, but also what will happen going forward. 

The first question we need to ask is whether there has been a change in the outlook for US permanent income. 

That is essentially whether there has been a drop in the US long-term growth potential. One can of course say that this pandemic will cause all kinds of frictions both as a result of changed behavior and changes in regulation. However, I think it is very hard to say now, but I would also stress that I think commentators in general make far too wild predictions about just how much this really is going to change things. 

Right now it is much easier to say “everything will change – nothing will be the same” in the global ‘media contest’, while the most likely scenario that we will gradually adapt as humanity always does and that this is likely to have an insignificant long-term effect on global growth will not get you either on CNN or Fox TV these days. 

Furthermore, judging from what the financial markets are telling us there is no reason that we should have become significantly more worried about long-term growth in the US or globally because of this pandemic.

This means that it is reasonable to assume that there really hasn’t been a change to permanent income expectations in the US. 

But what we have seen is a shock to private consumption, but not because people have become overly worried about their future income in general (some clearly have), but because people simply haven’t been able to spend. Your favourite restaurant has been closed and so has your hairdresser. 

So what has been happening is that your actual private consumption has been lower than your ‘targeted consumption’. 

A way of illustrating this is by looking at consumption and bank deposits. If private consumption develops as planned then we should expect deposits to grow steadily (with income) over time. However, if there is a shock to private consumption then this should be reflected by a similar shock to bank deposits. 

The graph below shows that the lockdowns and the behavioral reaction to the perception of the risks of the coronavirus in the US have had exactly this effect.

Deposits PCE

We see that prior to the shock bank deposits and private consumption expenditure was growing much in line with a strong positive correlation. However, as the ‘lockdown shock’ hit consumption dropped like a stone while deposits increased sharply. 

It is particularly noteworthy that in dollar terms the increase from February to April bank deposits nearly is exactly the same amount as the decline in private consumption in March. 

We don’t have the April numbers for private consumption yet but given the continued increase in bank deposits we should expect private consumption to have declined a further in April.

This to me is a pretty clear indication that the drop in US private consumption does not primarily reflect worries about the future permanent income of US consumers or a negative shock to income itself (then deposits would have dropped and not increased). But rather this is simply a reflection of the fact that US consumers have been taking temporary ‘vacation’ from spending. 

The question of course is when will consumers start to spend again?

Here history might help us. There are not a lot of examples in US modern economic history of such ‘unplanned spending vacations’, but one example is very similar and that is 911. 

When terror hit the US on September 11 2001 the US economy in many ways also came under a ‘lockdown’ and Americans stopped spending from one day to another. 

It was a shock many at the time said American consumers would never recover from – in the same way many today say that it will take a very long time to return to ‘normal’ consumption patterns. 

The stories at the time were the same as today – people will never fly again, they will not go to restaurants, they will never go to a basketball game again etc. 

We today know that the shock didn’t have a very long-lasting impact on US consumers. 

The graph below shows the consumption-deposit-shock of 2001. 

911 deposits PCE

We see the 911-consumption-deposit-shock is quite similar to what we are seeing now. 911 caused a ‘spending lockdown’ in September-October 2011, which in turn caused bank deposits to increase in parallel. 

However, the cut in spending had not been planned and consumers had not changed their permanent income expectations and consequently consumers quickly got consumption and deposits back on their ‘targeted’ levels  – indicated by the dotted lines. 

In fact, nearly to the dollar the amount US consumers ‘under-spend’ in September 2001 they ‘over-spend’ in October 2001. And they had the money in their accounts to do it. 

After having made up for ‘lost’ consumption consumers got back on track in November and continued on the pre-911 spending path.  

Those of us who still in horror remember the terror attacks on that horrible day in September 2001 also remember the fear of flying and the fear of just going out and about. However, life returned and so did consumption – in less than a month. 

I believe this is an important lesson for those who think that ‘we will never be back to how it was before’ in terms of consumption. 

If economic theory (the permanent income hypothesis) and economic history (911) teaches us anything it is that we should expect US consumption to make a very swift recovery.

In fact there is no reason not to believe that private consumption expenditure will be back on track in July after likely overshooting in June as US consumers catch up on what they have ‘lost’ in terms of spending since February.  

Another reason to be optimistic is what we are now seeing in terms of private consumption in the Nordic countries. 

Private consumption has followed a very similar pattern as US consumption in March and April in all of the Nordic countries. We are, however, now beginning to get out of lockdown.

In Denmark schools and kindergartens have been (partly) open since Easter and over the last two weeks certain shops that were closed (by government regulation) during the lockdown have reopened – for example hairdressers. 

My former colleagues at Danske Bank publishes a weekly “Spending Monitor”, which is based on among other things the bank’s clients’ credit card and cellphone payments. The Spending Monitor gives a near-real time update on Danish private consumption. 

It will be very interesting to follow in the coming weeks as Denmark opens up more and more for business and as we return to a more normal life. The ‘re-emergence’ has been under way over the past month. 

A very notable graph in the latest edition of Danske’s “Spending Monitor” is this graph with the turnover at hairdressers.

I particularly note that not only have Danes returned to the hairdressers – they are also making up for lost ground (and long hair) and spending around 20-30% more at the hairdresser than a year ago. 

I believe we will see something very similar overall in the US as the US economy also re-emerges from lockdown in the coming weeks and I see no reason why private consumption shouldn’t recover very fast. 

Yes, US unemployment will drop below 6% by November

So in conclusion, I think that despite the tragedy of the Covid-19 epidemic there is no reason to believe that the US economy – and the global economy for that matter – shouldn’t recover quite fast from this crisis. Much faster than after the 2008-9 crisis. 

Numerous policy mistakes have been made around the world both in combating and containing the pandemic and in terms of the monetary and fiscal response to the crisis and more mistakes are likely to be made, but we should nonetheless remember that market economies emerge much faster from negative supply shocks than from demand shocks. 

That is what I have tried to argue is this blog post and finally let me repeat my forecast – I strongly believe that US unemployment will drop very fast in the coming months and will likely have dropped below 6% when US voters vote at the US presidential elections in November.  

 ——

Contacts:

Lars Christensen, LC@mamoadvisory.com, +45 52 50 25 06.

See my profile at my Danish speaker agency here.

Leave a comment

69 Comments

  1. Michael

     /  May 11, 2020

    Are you willing to bet on this prediction?

    I think the return to normalcy will be sticker than you think. Lots of places are closing permanently, and starting up those businesses again will take time. That means there will be downstream consequences to suppliers, etc. Some had already been arguing we were due for a recession anyway. Private investment was already starting to drop for two quarters, and historical 10-2 treasury spreads were suggesting a recession around the corner. The two effects could mix together to result in a longer time to reallocate resources across the proper chains of production. Considering we basically have no price signals for large parts of the economy right now, this suggests to me recover will take longer than you think.

    Reply
    • contactngdpadviserscom

       /  May 11, 2020

      No need to bet with Lars. There is an enormous betting market already out there. Just go short the S&P500, it quick easy and cheap. And will pay up if you right and Lars (and the market) are wrong.

      Reply
      • Michael

         /  May 27, 2020

        The market seems to be fairly confident in how things are, but the market doesn’t need unemployment to be under 6% to be doing this well. Betting helps to better keep experts accountable for their predictions. Their record is better kept, and they put explicit skin in the game regarding the specific prediction. The market can do great or poorly regardless of whether the 6% condition is met anyway – I care about the specific prediction.

  2. Sant

     /  May 11, 2020

    Hi Lars,

    Two points must not be overlooked: 1- 6% is not what it used to be. Look at the labor participation rate dynamics for the past several decades. Demographics are in charge as well but many people will drop out of the labor market in the near term driving the jobless rate down. 2- We still have not seen the new regulations. Service sector can hardly return to it’s pre-virus employment level if we see strict rgulations for airlines, restaurants, gym etc. Economists or the markets can celeberate 6% however the labor market will not. Take care and stay safe.

    Reply
  3. Matthias

     /  May 11, 2020

    What about the increased unemployment benefits in the US? Those seems to be paying people to stay out of work.

    In many cases, people make more unemployed than in their previous jobs.

    Though from what I’ve read, the current legislation responsible for that runs out in August. So unemployment might be back down in time for the election.

    Reply
  4. Michael Culbert

     /  May 11, 2020

    Your entire analysis is based on the unfounded fact that the virus goes away. What planet are you living on. The virus will be with us (herd immunity will not reach 55% with or without a vaccine for at least 12 to 24 months) well beyond November. As much as the pent up demand to socialize is on display this will recorrect after the public understands that the virus is still very much active. You should make an attempt at analyzing the true variables, virus transmission rates, service sector economy which has never experienced a supply shut down that ultimately affects the demand side. Your work is very misleading and just wrong.

    Reply
    • Nathan

       /  May 11, 2020

      The virus is not going away until there is a vaccine.

      Reply
    • Matthias

       /  May 12, 2020

      Well, even without a vaccine, you should be able to get the infection down to the same levels as Hong Kong or Taiwan or New Zealand. They didn’t have any silver bullet or magic wand.

      Reply
      • Paul

         /  May 12, 2020

        But they had competent leadership and adequate testing and contact tracing, something the US will never have.

  5. Josh

     /  May 11, 2020

    I think some excellent points are made in the article, but when you say “there is no reason to believe that the US economy shouldn’t recover quite fast from this” wouldn’t the virus not going away or re-spiking be a reason? The front heavy unemployment here is a great point to differentiate this crisis from the recession, and adds some rationale to market recovery, but there is a problem with some of the logic here. After 9/11, there was a short sharp drop in demand. Katrina is also used as an example. These are a 1 day and one week event. After they were over, the threat of such a disaster happening was more well known, but the disaster was gone. We were more prepared for the next one. In this case the hurricane is roaring overhead. We don’t know if the eye has passed yet. We think so, but we don’t know. We don’t know if the storm will quit as fast as it came. As the economy opens up we could have a spike in cases that leave us half opened for the next year. Then you wouldn’t see 6% unemployment in November. What if we successfully open without a spike and this winter it comes roaring back and we all lockdown again? Wouldn’t that cause a bigger crash? This argument is a good optimistic argument, but it appears to me to ignore even an average case scenario and especially a worst case scenario for the virus. It’s a best case scenario argument that assumes the virus will largely go away and not come back enough to hurt the economy further.

    Reply
  6. rando34

     /  May 12, 2020

    I am certainly sympathetic to the wisdom-of-crowds argument — the market knows best, and predicts a quick recovery. But I have a hard time believing things will get back to normal quickly. I have no argument for why the market does not reflect that though. I know…lame.

    My other point is that your graph comparing PCE and bank deposits does not seem to support your overall theory: “Lockdowns caused the downturn”. The drop in pCE happens a full month, if not more, before any lockdowns are in place. I’m not sure how you conclude that things will return to normal when the lockdowns are removed. And you say that PCE dropped almost dollar for dollar as deposits grew, but the graph doesn’t show that at all. PCE appears to drop 3 times the amount that deposits grew during the period in question. Your interpretation of that one graph leads me to question many of your other assumptions.

    Reply
  7. Chris

     /  May 12, 2020

    “Southern Europeans go on Summer vacation typically in August” … and, what do they do on vacation? They spend money and consume.

    “private consumption … fluctuates wildly before and after Christmas” … and, what do people do at Christmas? They spend money and consume.

    These are poor comparisons to the current situation in which people are not working, not consuming, and debts are mounting. We have both supply and demand shocks at the moment.

    Many of your examples are cherry-picking the part you agree with and leaving out some pretty important details. For example, comparing the stock market performance to unemployment. Maybe you should look at market performance since the peak in February. We are down 15% which means your blue dot should be on the other side of the y-axis. Instead, you are isolating the bear market relief rally that is about to pivot and fall off a cliff.

    This is not well-constructed analysis in my opinion.

    Reply
  8. stoneybatter

     /  May 12, 2020

    Lars, how do you explain the fact that markets are also telling us that the Fed’s policy rate will be near-zero for years and inflation will be far below-target for years?

    This is a negative demand shock and the Fed is not doing enough to balance the shock, meaning demand will be persistently below its optimal level for longer than just this summer. I believe this is the “market monetarist” conclusion.

    Reply
  9. mayank

     /  May 12, 2020

    Could you share the data source for state by state initial unemployment claims? Curious what the other states not included in your graph look like today as well. Very interesting model, thanks for highlighting.

    Reply
  10. Joseph Sameh

     /  May 14, 2020

    A recession is 2 quarters not a summer vacation or January doldrums. Your hypothesis needs a pivot to reality.

    Reply
  11. “This basically means that workers are being laid-off not because they have become too “expensive” relative to output prices (that is what is happening with a demand shock), but because the cost of OTHER inputs have increased.”
    The profit maximising level of employment is where the marginal product of labour is equal to the real wage? mpl(No) = W/P?
    For workers to be laid-off something must have changed? They must have ‘become too “expensive” relative to output prices’?

    Reply
  12. Michael

     /  October 5, 2020

    Seems like I was right when I left my first comment here. The unemployment rate before the election is at 7.9%. More unemployment data won’t come out before the election (final BLS publishing date before the election should have been accounted for in the prediction), and even if it did, another drop of 1.9% seems unlikely.
    I should admit I am pleasantly surprised by the speed of the recovery, but ultimately the specific prediction in the post was wrong.

    Reply
  13. Colin Mason

     /  November 3, 2020

    Not quite. Last unemployment measurement was 7.9%.

    Reply
  1. Newsletter: From Furloughs to Factory Closings – nomore10minutebreaks
  2. Newsletter: From Furloughs to Factory Closings – Finance Market House
  3. Monday assorted links - Marginal REVOLUTION
  4. Here’s Why the Dow Didn’t Crash Despite This Grisly COVID-19 Milestone – Virus Not OK
  5. Here’s Why the Dow Didn’t Crash Despite This Grisly COVID-19 Milestone - Loyal World News
  6. Here’s Why the Dow Didn’t Crash Despite This Grisly COVID-19 Milestone | Bitcoinfolio
  7. Here's Why the Dow Didn't Crash Despite This Grisly COVID-19 Milestone - My Hot News Pakistan
  8. Here’s Why the Dow Didn’t Crash Despite This Grisly COVID-19 Milestone – Without Technology
  9. Here’s Why the Dow Didn’t Crash Despite This Grisly COVID-19 Milestone - Bitcoin News Plus
  10. Here’s Why the Dow Didn’t Crash Despite This Grisly COVID-19 Milestone – Coin Summit
  11. Heres Why the Dow Didnt Crash Despite This Grisly COVID-19 Milestone – Totally news
  12. Newsletter: From Furloughs to Factory Closings | Share Market Pro
  13. Here’s Why the Dow Didn’t Crash Despite This Grisly COVID-19 Milestone – Crypto Mining
  14. Here’s Why the Dow Didn’t Crash Despite This Grisly COVID-19 Milestone – My Crypto
  15. General update, May 11 | askblog
  16. Here’s Why the Dow Didn’t Crash Despite This Grisly COVID-19 Milestone – Accu-rate
  17. Here's Why the Dow Didn't Crash Despite This Grisly COVID-19 Milestone | CoinCrankerz
  18. Here’s Why the Dow Didn’t Crash Despite This Grisly COVID-19 Milestone – Digital Coin Owner
  19. Here’s Why the Dow Didn’t Crash Despite This Grisly COVID-19 Milestone - CoinPress
  20. Here’s Why the Dow Didn’t Crash Despite This Grisly COVID-19 Milestone – Fund via Crypto
  21. Cryptocurrency News This is Why the Dow Did not Shatter No matter This Terrifying COVID-19 Milestone - INFOSHRI
  22. Here’s Why the Dow Didn’t Crash Despite This Grisly COVID-19 Milestone – African Investors In Diaspora Association (AIDA)
  23. Here’s Why the Dow Didn’t Crash Despite This Grisly COVID-19 Milestone | Crypto News | AnotherFN.com – Another FN
  24. Right here’s Why the Dow Didn’t Fracture No matter This Shocking COVID-19 Milestone - CryptoNews Inside
  25. Depression 2020? | Bayesian Investor Blog
  26. Here’s Why the Dow Didn’t Crash Despite This Grisly COVID-19 Milestone – Breaking News
  27. Will we have a depression? - Econlib
  28. Will we have a depression? – Church Security
  29. Will we have a depression? | Share Market Pro
  30. Will we have a depression? – Finance Market House
  31. Will we have a depression? – CNB Reports
  32. TheMoneyIllusion » Why are stocks doing well?
  33. Why Are Stocks Doing Well? – Conservative Investing News
  34. Why Are Stocks Doing Well? - Newsarific
  35. Why Are Stocks Doing Well? - Stockmarket Insights, Stockmarket Quotes, Financial News, Trading Ideas, Research
  36. Why Are Stocks Doing Well? – The Conservative Investor Daily
  37. The shortest recession ever – unemployment will be below 6% in November | The Market Monetarist
  38. May Jobs Report Hints More Spending Isn’t Answer in Economic Recovery
  39. May Jobs Report Shows Why More Government Isn’t The Answer For Economic Recovery - Here's The "Build The Wall Hat" You Want | Walls-Work.org
  40. Canli Casino Oyna – Bahsegel| En İyi Türkçe Online Casino Sitesi
  41. May Jobs Report Shows Why More Government Isn’t the Answer for Economic Recovery - Dr. Rich Swier
  42. May Jobs Report Shows Why More Government Isn’t the Answer for Economic Recovery – DonnyFerguson.com
  43. May Jobs Report Shows Why More Government Isn’t the Answer for Economic Recovery – FREE SPEECH DAILY
  44. All Hail Lars Christensen! – BIJIN WORLD
  45. All Hail Lars Christensen! - Breaking News log
  46. All Hail Lars Christensen! – Viral News Connection
  47. All Hail Lars Christensen! – CNB Reports
  48. All Hail Lars Christensen! – Econlib | Bishnupriya Manipuri
  49. All Hail Lars Christensen! - Econlib
  50. Lessons From the Past - The Money MischiefThe Money Mischief

Leave a Reply to contactngdpadviserscomCancel reply

Discover more from The Market Monetarist

Subscribe now to keep reading and get access to the full archive.

Continue reading